Monday, December 7, 2015

SOME IDEAS FOR THE COMING BUDGET

From Business World of 31 January 2005.


Fiscal transparency


The finance minister has completed the consultations preceding the budget: he has heard agriculturists and industrialists, economists and trade unionists, Congressmen and backwoodsmen. He has conferred with his top bureaucrats. He has before him the major proposals and hundreds of minor ones. The outlines of budget are discernible; now he only has to put his stamp on it.
The major fiscal reforms were completed in the 1990s, some of them by him. This year will see what might be the last of them – the introduction of value added tax (VAT). But it is a toss-up whether those affected will see it as a reform or a turn of the screw. Tax authorities in this country are seen as arbitrary and corrupt; will this perception change? Business taxpayers will have to claim rebates for the tax paid on the inputs purchased by them; each rebate will give the excise and sales tax authorities a chance to deny it, to harass taxpayers and ask for bribes. The scope for oppression under VAT will be much greater than under the present regime; the success or failure of the experiment will depend on what safeguards the finance minister introduces against the oppression. The finance minister should apply his formidable legal brain to them, for they will make his reputation – or make people want to forget him.
The finance minister takes the commitments he took on under the Fiscal ResponsibilityAct seriously; he devoted most of the ministry’s mid-term review to his performance on it, even though it was not such as to bring him credit. If he wants to leave behind a permanent improvement in the way the country manages its finances, he should change the fiscal deficit targets: instead of expressing them as percentages of GDP, he should adopt absolute targets. The ultimate aim is to reach zero revenue or fiscal deficit; it is the same whether it is expressed in absolute or relative terms. GDP figures are known with a lag of a year; the ratios put out by the finance ministry are based on advance estimates, which are approximate and can be biased. If the finance minister lays down absolute numerical targets for the next four years, he will have a precise limit he can use to impose absolute budgetary constraints on each ministry. It will not only make achievement of the overall deficit target easier, but it will also tell ministers in no uncertain terms within what figure they have to get through the year. The finance minister may leave a figure in the budget for contingencies and for discretionary spending by the Prime Minister; but at least the scope for arbitrariness would then be limited to the PMO.
Another reform that is overdue is to replace the fiscal deficit targets by those for the total borrowings of the public sector. Spending out of borrowings by public sector enterprises (PSEs) adds as surely to demand as does spending by ministries; fiscal repairs must cover them too. Britain has for long framed targets in terms of Public Sector Borrowing Requirements; this is a concept we should adopt as well. There will be violent opposition to this; many socialists and pseudo-socialists in the government will argue that  PSEs are independent entities, and that their borrowings should not be treated as a part of the central deficit. But the fact is, that if those PSEs default on their debt, the central government will bale them out. And should they need capital, they do not have the freedom to go and raise equity in the market. As long as the guarantee and the restriction on equity issues remain, PSEs are an inalienable part of the central government.
This point gains added significance when we come to the states. For the states’ finances have been in a much more parlous state than the centre’s; and many of them have been borrowing through their PSEs and spending the money to pay their employees’ salaries. This is a most unhealthy practice; the way to bring it out in the open is to combine their own and their PSEs’ borrowings.
Finally, the finance minister should think of creating an internal credit market for the central government. Money is released to spending ministries on 1 April; the next three months see a huge excess of expenditure over revenue. Income tax flows in between July and October when returns become due; at this time, the balance is reversed. Then, as the end of the year approaches, ministries hasten to spend their budgets, and the deficit again increases. A mechanism can be conceived by which ministries would be expected to spend evenly through the year, and deviations from the pattern would either earn or cost interest. The interest could even be determined by bargaining between ministries with surplus and deficit funds.