While in Stanford, I completed a study of the Indian software industry {http://web.stanford.edu/group/siepr/cgi-bin/siepr/?q=system/files/shared/pubs/papers/pdf/credpr70.pdf) in 2001. This is a summary that went into columns of Business Standard. The software industry put Bangalore on the world IT map, and made south India richer than the north for the first time in centuries. It had nothing to do with the 1991 reforms; but if we regard the reforms as a success today (leading to high growth uninterrupted by payments crises), that success has a good deal to do with the rise of the IT industry. The BJP government was friendly and supportive of the software industry, but it was pretty clueless on macroeconomics, to which I gave it space in this series.
The Peril and the Promise
I The Terrifying Prospects of Good Fortune
India’s software exports in 1999-2000 were expected to
reach $3.9 billion – 6 per cent of its current account receipts. That is not
much. But India’s richest man in 1999 (in terms of publicly known assets) was
Azim H Premji, the principal shareholder of Wipro, a software exporter; Wipro
had the largest market capitalization in the Indian corporate world. K R Narayana Murthy of Infosys was No 4 and B
Ramalinga Raju of Satyam was No 12 in the list; their software companies were
also amongst the most valuable in the Indian stock market. Further, software
exports had grown 51 per cent a year since 1993-94. Projection of this growth
into the not-too-far future leads to startling conclusions about the share of
software in the Indian exports and economy.
The sudden riches and the glowing prospects have
focused public attention in India on the software industry. The Government of
India set up a Ministry of Information Technology and appointed a Task Force to
work out an Information Technology Action Plan. Its report starts with the
following words:
The government of India, recognizing that the impressive growth the
country has achieved since the mid-Eighties in Information Technology is still
a small proportion of the potential to achieve, has resolved to make India a
Global IT Superpower and a front-runner in the age of Information Revolution…
I share the belief of the industry and the political
leaders that the industry will continue to grow rapidly, and that its growth
can contribute to a break with India’s lackluster record of overall growth and
human development. But there are different growth paths, some more promising
than others; it is worth examining the path chosen by the establishment and
considering alternatives. Specifically, the government, in collaboration with
the software industry, has chalked out a strategy that is sure to fail: it will
damp down the growth of software exports and severely limit the broader
economic benefits resulting from it. To exploit the software success, India
needs to make radical changes in its macroeconomic policies – before it is too
late.
In an industry that is growing so rapidly,
considerable fluctuations in the growth rate are to be expected. Actually, however,
the growth of software sales, both at home and abroad, has been fairly stable:
in the past six years, the annual growth rate of exports has fluctuated between
47 and 61 per cent, of domestic sales between 31 and 52 per cent, and of total
sales between 43 and 54 per cent. These figures do not suggest an industry
being tossed about in a turbulent sea of competition; rather, it is an industry
that faces an enormous market but whose expansion is constrained by supply
factors – principally by the output of reliable software engineers and their
retention by the industry. As the industry grows, this constraint will continue
to dominate. I shall discuss it later. But for the moment, I wish to work out
the implications of assuming that the growth rates of the recent past will
persist, and compare them with the projections of NASSCOM.
NASSCOM projects exports to grow to $50 billion and
home sales to $87 billion in 2008-2009; these projections are adopted in the
official IT plan. They imply annual growth rates from 1998-89 of 32 per cent
for exports and 55 per cent for home sales
– just the reverse of the past rates, for between 1993-94 and 1999-2000,
exports rose 51 per cent a year, and domestic sales 30 per cent a year.
NASSCOM gives no reason for the export pessimism or
the domestic optimism. But a likely reason becomes apparent if one projects
software exports at the past rates. If software exports continue to rise at
50.9 per cent per annum, they will reach $158 billion in 2008-09. If payments
for visible and invisible imports continue to rise at 7.6 per cent – the
average rate between 1990-91 and 1999-2000 – they will reach $138 billion. In
other words, India could very well finance all its imports of goods and
services from exports of software alone by that year. If nothing else changed,
it would not need any other exports – or foreign investment. And if other
exports continued and foreign investment kept coming in, India would have to
increase its import intensity. If it did not, it is very likely to catch the
Dutch disease. It is already possible to discern its first signs: as Figure 1
shows, industrial growth as well as growth of commodity exports have slowed
down, while reserves continue to grow.
The software industry has grown so fast that
small variations in its projected growth rates make a large difference to its
volume. The implications of the growth rates of the recent past continuing into
the future are brought out more starkly by Figure 2: they imply that software
exports alone will exceed all current account payments by 2008-9, and GDP in
2013-14. The idea that the software industry may dominate the economy and the
balance of payments daunts people – especially those in the government and the
establishment who mistake conservatism for realism.
There is nothing to worry about if the emerging trends
disturb the establishment; as reality unfolds, the disturbance will pass. But
if, as a result, the establishment takes steps to thwart the trends, especially
such an exhilarating trend as software exports exhibit, it would no longer be
acting in the national interest.
Let me spell it out more starkly. This is what Arun
Jaitley is reported to have said at a recent BJP meeting:
If there is one road map of the Vajpayee government, it
is to free the country from the shackles that prevented the flourishing of
entrepreneurship. We want Indians to do as well within India as they do when
they go abroad. The government can no longer be involved in areas it is not
supposed to. India missed the industrial revolution, and this government is
committed not to let the IT revolution pass us by.
There are many other signs of the government’s
friendship towards industry: its ministers’ attendance of industry events,
their openness to requests from industry, the Prime Minister’s Industrial
Advisory Council – and the steady rise in industrial protection. In the
circumstances, it is possible that this protection, which is the cement that
holds together the alliance of the party and industry, will hasten the onset of
the Dutch disease and abort the software revolution.
It is also possible that the entire thrust towards the
domestic market that is embodied both in NASSCOM’s projections and the
recommendations of the Task Force on Information Technology emanates from a
lack of confidence that the export trend can be maintained, and seeks to
change the direction of the industry’s development in favour of the domestic
market. Is it trying to do so? To discover this, we need to look more closely
at the Information Technology Plan.
II Information Technology Policy Framework
Two important documents have driven the government’s
policy towards support of the software industry: the Report of the IT Task
Force appointed by the Ministry of Information Technology, and the Report of
the Subject Group on Knowledge-based Industries prepared for the Prime
Minister’s Council of Industrialists. The two are very different. The IT Plan
was prepared in a great hurry, and much of it was implemented – at least in
form if not in substance – with equal haste. It consists entirely of nostrums:
no analysis, no argument, no consideration of alternatives. The Subject Group’s
report covers a broader area – although the Group would have liked to think in
terms of the application of knowledge to all industries, it was really thinking
in terms of information technology and pharmaceuticals – and it was more
knowledgeable about the former than the latter. Whereas the IT Plan was
blatantly designed to favour the IT industry, the Subject Group tried to take a
fairer, economy-wide view.
The IT Plan is divided into three parts on software,
hardware and a national long-term policy. They simply list points of action to
be taken – 108 on software, 84 on hardware and 131 on long-term policy. A
classification of these points is given in the accompanying table. It shows
that there is some truth to the supposition that the Plan is directed towards
creating domestic demand for information technology: 15 recommendations of the
software plan and 13 of the long-term plan are designed to expand the domestic
market. Most involve computerization by the central government and in
institutions under its control. There are other recommendations that, though
not directly directed at market expansion, would in effect do so – for
instance, recommendations to set up government data banks and to spend
government money.
But market expansion is not the primary thrust of the
Plan. Almost as many of its recommendations are directed at improving the
supply and quality of engineers. If the Plan has a thrust, it is towards
getting the government out of the industry’s hair; almost a third of the
recommendations call for legal changes and simplification and relaxation of
rules. And these recommendations for debureaucratization and leniency are
concentrated in the area of foreign trade and payments, accounting for almost
half of them. Admittedly, most of them come from the Plan for computer
hardware; this industry, which has suffered considerably from import
liberalization in the past nine years, is not asking for protection, but for
debureaucratization of imports so that it can compete more effectively in the
domestic and export markets. On the whole, the thrust of the report is not
towards growth within a protected domestic market; if at all, it is towards a
level playing field for competing with the IT industry elsewhere.
The Action Plan is best read together with the Report
of the Subject Group on Knowledge-based Industries (2000). There is
considerable overlap between the two. The main areas in which both seek action
are the following (those on which action is already completed, for instance the
regulation and taxation of employee stock options, are omitted):
Labour laws:
The Subject Group on Knowledge-based Industries sought exemption from a host of
rules relating to labour: rules limiting the number of hours, specifying hours
of rest and minimum leave, requiring that wages be paid in cash, that walls and
staircases be whitewashed once a year, etc etc. The IT Task Force had little to
say on this; presumably the government representatives ensured that this
embarrassing subject was kept out.
Labour supply:
The industry is concerned about the shortage of software engineers, and many of
the recommendations are directed towards raising the supply and enhancing the
quality of education. The Subject Group was concerned about improving all
education. The IT Task Force had numerous recommendations on training – almost
arguing that every child should become computer-literate – at government
expense of course – even before it could learn to read and write.
Customs and import control: Import duties on computer hardware and peripherals
are substantial, but software exporters can avoid them by setting themselves up
in zones specializing in exports or by promising to export services worth a
multiple of their equipment imports. Movement of equipment out of export zones
is policed; and licences to import against export undertakings involve red tape
in their issue. These bureaucratic restrictions should be removed. The Action
Plan proposed a new entity called the Soft-bonded Unit. Essentially, it called
for an end to all policing, and to reliance instead on ex-post audits to ensure
that export undertakings have been met. This was because it covered both the
hardware and software industries. The software industry more or less avoids
customs and import control, so the Subject Group had little to say on these.
Exchange control: Exporting companies should be freed from exchange control in respect
of investment and divestment abroad by Indian companies, allowable expenses
abroad and the use of credit cards. At present they are allowed to hold dollar
accounts, but there are many vexatious restrictions on how money in these
accounts may be spent; these restrictions should be relaxed. The Subject Group was more concerned
about exchange control.
Finance:
Apart from more finance from government banks and term lending institutions,
the industry wants them not to seek collateral in the form of fixed assets, and
instead to fund IT companies on the basis of their turnover.
It is typical for lobbies to ask for special favours
and for the government to grant them. But such special favours to particular
industries are undesirable for four reasons.
First, they greatly complicate the laws.
Every law gets cluttered up with a string of exceptions.
Second, they give increased discretion to
the bureaucracy that administers those laws: it can quibble about whether a
particular favour is due to a particular firm in the particular circumstances,
the quibbling can lead to delays, those who suffer from it bring extraneous
pressures – “influence” – to bear on the bureaucracy, and where the political
establishment and the bureaucracy are prone to corruption, exceptions expand
the scope for it.
Third, they are generally discretionary
and unfair to the excluded industries.
And finally,
they reduce the impact of the relaxations by excluding other industries which
might have proved equally responsive to them. Hence it is worth asking, in the
case of all demands of industry lobbies, whether the concessions should not be
extended to everyone.
Perfectly general changes of regime are desirable in
all the above areas; I shall explore in the succeeding articles what they might
be. Both the reports were prepared by industrialists, who have no clue about
macroeconomics. And it is macroeconomics that is likely to turn the software
boom into a crash unless it is handled correctly; I shall describe what that
handling involves.
Finally, even if there were a general relaxation of
the controls that will become dysfunctional, it would not resolve all problems.
It is in the nature of economies that there are conflicts amongst macroeconomic
objectives, certain strategic choices have to be made, and no particular strategy
is inherently and permanently superior. I would also try to point out this
vestige of indeterminacy in optimum policies.
Recommendations of the Action Plan of the IT Task Force
|
|||||||||||||||
Part
I
|
Part
II
|
Part
III
|
Total
|
Part
I
|
Part
II
|
Part
III
|
Total
|
||||||||
Per cent
|
|||||||||||||||
Laws
|
4
|
6
|
3
|
14
|
3.7
|
7.1
|
2.3
|
4.3
|
|||||||
Company law
|
1
|
4
|
5
|
0.9
|
4.8
|
1.5
|
|||||||||
Other laws
|
3
|
2
|
3
|
9
|
2.8
|
2.4
|
2.3
|
2.8
|
|||||||
Simplification of rules
|
11
|
27
|
18
|
56
|
10.19
|
32.14
|
12.98
|
17.34
|
|||||||
Central government
|
5
|
5
|
16
|
26
|
4.6
|
6.0
|
12.2
|
8.0
|
|||||||
Customs
|
3
|
20
|
1
|
24
|
2.8
|
23.8
|
0.8
|
7.4
|
|||||||
Other
|
3
|
2
|
1
|
6
|
2.8
|
2.4
|
1.9
|
||||||||
Relaxation of rules
|
9
|
21
|
15
|
45
|
8.3
|
25.0
|
11.5
|
13.9
|
|||||||
Exchange control
|
4
|
12
|
5
|
21
|
3.7
|
14.3
|
3.8
|
6.5
|
|||||||
Banks and financial institutions
|
1
|
9
|
10
|
0.9
|
6.9
|
3.1
|
|||||||||
Commerce ministry
|
1
|
6
|
7
|
0.9
|
7.1
|
2.2
|
|||||||||
Other
|
3
|
3
|
1
|
7
|
2.8
|
3.6
|
0.8
|
2.1
|
|||||||
Favours
|
24
|
19
|
7
|
50
|
22.22
|
22.62
|
4.58
|
15.48
|
|||||||
Central government subsidies
|
1
|
2
|
2
|
5
|
0.9
|
2.4
|
1.5
|
1.5
|
|||||||
Increase in financing
|
5
|
3
|
4
|
12
|
4.6
|
3.6
|
3.1
|
3.7
|
|||||||
Reduction in customs duty
|
1
|
7
|
8
|
0.9
|
8.3
|
2.5
|
|||||||||
Reduction in income tax
|
7
|
7
|
6.5
|
2.2
|
|||||||||||
Reduction in excise duty
|
1
|
4
|
5
|
0.9
|
4.8
|
1.5
|
|||||||||
Other
|
9
|
3
|
1
|
13
|
8.3
|
3.6
|
4.0
|
||||||||
Market expansion
|
15
|
1
|
13
|
29
|
13.9
|
1.2
|
9.9
|
9.0
|
|||||||
By central government
|
7
|
1
|
13
|
21
|
6.5
|
1.2
|
9.9
|
6.5
|
|||||||
By telecommunications
|
6
|
6
|
5.6
|
1.9
|
|||||||||||
By armed forces
|
2
|
2
|
1.9
|
0.6
|
|||||||||||
Training
|
16
|
12
|
28
|
14.8
|
9.2
|
8.7
|
|||||||||
Expansion
|
12
|
9
|
21
|
11.1
|
6.9
|
6.5
|
|||||||||
Standards and quality improvement
|
4
|
3
|
7
|
3.7
|
2.3
|
2.2
|
|||||||||
Greater competition
|
6
|
1
|
7
|
5.6
|
1.2
|
2.2
|
|||||||||
Other government support
|
18
|
1
|
42
|
61
|
16.67
|
0
|
32.06
|
18.89
|
|||||||
New institutions
|
13
|
13
|
9.9
|
4.0
|
|||||||||||
Supply of information
|
4
|
9
|
13
|
3.7
|
6.9
|
4.0
|
|||||||||
Greater expenditure
|
6
|
4
|
10
|
5.6
|
3.1
|
3.1
|
|||||||||
Enforcement of standards
|
8
|
8
|
6.1
|
2.5
|
|||||||||||
Financing of research
|
1
|
5
|
6
|
0.9
|
3.8
|
1.9
|
|||||||||
Computer security and censorship
|
5
|
1
|
6
|
4.6
|
0.8
|
1.9
|
|||||||||
Other
|
2
|
1
|
2
|
5
|
1.9
|
1.5
|
1.5
|
||||||||
Bullshit
|
6
|
9
|
21
|
36
|
5.6
|
10.7
|
16.0
|
11.1
|
|||||||
108
|
84
|
131
|
323
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
||||||||
III Labour laws
The changes called for by the Subject Group on
Knowledge-based Industries and the Task Force on IT Action Plan fall into three
categories:
(i)
Relaxation in rules on working conditions: The Shops and
Commercial Establishments Act 1961 and the rules framed under it limit working
hours to no more than 9 a day and 48 a week, require a break to be given at
least once every 5 hours, limit the total length of a working day to no more
than 12 hours in a day, and require that hours worked beyond 9 a day or 48 a
week must be paid for at twice the normal wage. (How a worker not allowed to
work overtime can earn overtime may be a mystery to a lay reader, but poses no
difficulty to lawyers). The hours of work and wage rates have to be displayed,
as also the applicable minimum wage and dearness allowance (cost-of-living
adjustment). Every worker who has worked more than 240 days must be given one
day’s leave for every 20 days he works. Before he goes on leave, he has to be
paid wages in advance for the leave period. Advances may not exceed two months’
wages with the Labour Inspector’s permission. Every establishment must
whitewash all inside walls, passages and staircases with lime and paint all
internal structural iron and steelwork at least once a year, and maintain a
record of the dates of such whitewash and painting. Wages can be paid only in
coins or currency. Registers have to be maintained to record attendance, the
hours worked, overtime, leave taken with wages, dates of whitewash and
painting, fines or deductions for damage or loss imposed on workers, and
advances.
(ii)
Permission to use contract and casual labour: Employers have sought to evade the rigours of the
laws by employing temporary labour. Temporary labour is legally defined as
employment lasting not more than 240 days out of a year. Thus employers both
employ a worker and dismiss him within 240 days, often temporarily; or they
engage a contractor to provide labour on contract. To prevent this, the
government passed a Contract Labour Abolition Act, which made contract labour
illegal in a wide range of circumstances. It also amended the Employees’ State
Insurance Act 1948 and the Employees’ Provident Fund Act 1952 to ensure that an
employer of contract labour, and not the contractor, became liable for paying
their health insurance and provident fund contributions. The Task Force
recommended that the Contract Labour Abolition Act should not apply to the IT
industry, and that temporary status should be defined as 720 days in three
years instead of 240 days in a year. It also asked that IT firms should be
allowed to dismiss 10 per cent of the employees in a year without permission.
The Subject Group asked that knowledge-based establishments should be exempted
from the liability for the health insurance and provident fund contributions of
contract employees.
The motivation of the Subject Group for asking to be
exempted from labour laws is clear: for the Group also asks that Labour
Inspectors should not keep dropping by to do the inspections done by other
Labour Inspectors already, should not waste the managers’ time, and should not
be so incompetent as to be mystified by computerized records. The real
grievance relates to the corruption amongst Labour Inspectors, who reapeatedly
visit software manufacturers in search of bribes.
However, the problems pointed out are not peculiar to
IT or knowledge-based industries, nor do they deserve exemption just for being
those. No employer should have to face them. There is a case for rethinking the
entire framework of labour legislation enacted by the first government of
independent India in the 1940s in imitation of similar legislation passed by
the Labour government in Britain. The relevant legislation is the following.
i.
The Shops and Commercial Establishments Act is outdated and needs to be repealed. Even industrial
countries that had similar laws have repealed or relaxed them. What the law
should insist on is that there should be a written contract between the
employer and the worker specifying the pay and working conditions; it should
help in the enforcement of such contracts, as well as of contracts between
trade unions and employers, by law courts. The regulation of working hours,
days, days of leave etc is unnecessary and counterproductive. Businesses would
have much better chances of surviving bad times if wages, hours and work
intensity were flexible.
ii.
The Industrial Disputes Act makes retrenchment impossible without the permission
of the relevant State government, which has been routinely denied. This single
measure has had enormous distortive effects. Establishments have kept below the
legal minimum (of 50 workers with power and 100 workers without power) to keep
out of its purview. Employers have dismissed workers within eight months so
that they would not become eligible for permanence. And they have hired workers
through contractors who can legally or illegally evade the ID Act.
The
solution must be looked for in minimum levels of retrenchment compensation that
would free establishments from having to seek permission. Thousands of workers
have been involved in the schemes of voluntary retirement and severance carried
out by firms in the past ten years. It would be helpful if their experience is
studied and summarized, and lessons drawn for a legislated set of rules for
minimum compensation.
iii.
The Employees’ Provident Fund Act: State-regulated pension provisions covered 34 million
salaried workers in 1998. Another 13 million salaried workers, 166 million
self-employed persons and 97 million casual or contract workers were uncovered.
Some of these could contribute to a Public Provident Fund Scheme operated
through banks, which also returned 12 per cent. The employees’ provident funds
allowed withdrawals under very generous conditions; so although they imposed
very high compulsory gross contributions, the net accumulation was very small.
The Expert
Group for Devising a Pension System found the investment pattern very
inefficient. It recommended that all the various schemes should be replaced by
individual retirement accounts with stringent provisions against premature
withdrawal, to be invested with any of six pension funds, each offering three
funds of varying level of risk, freely transferable across fund managers and
funds, and operated through any post office or bank. Thus, the direction of pension
reforms is now clear; instead of giving special concessions to the
knowledge-based industries, the government should proceed directly to general
pension reform.
iv.
The Employees’ State Insurance Act provides medical treatment to workers of the covered
establishments. It provides the umbrella for massive fraud by workers, doctors
and bureaucrats; except in Bombay and Calcutta it hardly provides any
worthwhile medical cover. Its working needs to be studied in some detail. In
this area, as in pensions, the direction is clear: we must move away from
state-administered, rigid structures to a scheme which is financed by
beneficiaries through defined contributions, which is independent of a job or
indeed of employment, and which relies upon the provision of services by
competing insurers.
IV Worries about labour supply
Cheap supply of skilled labour is the bedrock of the
Indian software industry.It is also the operative bottleneck. The industry is
extremely conscious of it; the Task Force’s recommendations on it border on
panic. Amongst its suggestions are the following:
(i)
All students,
teachers and schools who want them would get computers from donations,
multilateral funds, large-scale imports at bargain prices and bank loans. So
would colleges, universities, polytechnics and hospitals. Universities would be
networked to provide distance education by 2000.
(ii)
Indian institutes
of technology and the Indian Institute of Science must triple their intake of
IT students. New institutes of information technology must be set up.
Information technology must be made compulsory for all degree courses and
introduced in some schools called smart schools. Schools in some districts that
have achieved universal literacy must achieve universal computer literacy. At
the other end, some educational centers in the most backward northern states
must be made models of IT-based education. The army would set up Information
Technology, System Engineering and IT Security Institutes. Soldiers being
retired from the army would be trained in information technology and sent off
into the villages.
(iii)
An Institute of
Computer Professionals would be set up as an accreditation body for degree
programmes.
(iv)
The Indian
institutes of management must set up courses in project management and software
marketing.
The Subject Group on Knowledge Industries is even more
ambitious: it aims at “restoring the glory of the Indian educational system
through a series of measures aimed at building a learning society”. Its agenda
is very diffuse, but the following are its major elements:
(i)
The government
should stop funding institutions of tertiary education, and should divert the
money to schools. Instead, they should charge commercial fees, and their
students should be given subsidized bank loans. They should draw funds from
companies, charitable trusts and international financial institutions.
Privately funded universities should be allowed. They should be given
operational and financial autonomy.
(ii)
Teachers’
salaries should be raised. Indians teaching abroad should be lured into them.
Half the appointments should be tenured; the rest of the teachers should come
from the relevant industry. Teachers should be encouraged to take consulting
assignments. Their research should be funded by industry and become
result-oriented.
(iii)
A national agency
to set educational standards should be set up. The bachelor’s degree should be
revamped to make it the basis for employment or academic specialization.
(iv)
Schoolteachers’
salaries should be raised. The syllabus for Bachelor of Education should be
modernized; teaching methods should move towards raising students’ interest and
involvement and encouraging them to discover, experiment and invent. English
should form an important part of the curriculum.
(v)
School syllabi
should be diversified to encourage streaming; children should be encouraged to
specialize in vocations.
The Subject Group’s otherwise excellent suggestions
have only a marginal relevance to the IT industry. The IT Action Plan is better
focused on the problems facing the software industry. But even then, the
connection between them and the solutions proposed is most fragile.
First, because the industry faces rapid labour
turnover, the firms have the impression of a grave labour shortage. But the
turnover only denotes a labour shortage; the magnitude of that labour shortage
is quite uncertain. There are similar complaints of manpower shortage in the
United States, which has been the subject of a series of official and
non-official studies. The most meticulous one, by Freeman and Aspray, examines
the various measures, including the rate of unemployment (which is less than
half the economy-wide unemployment rate), permanent labour certificates issued
by the Department of Labour, H1-B visas issued, and the rate of wage increase.
It concludes that a quantitative estimate of the labour shortage was not
possible.
It is natural for the industry to try to ensure that
there will be an abundance of qualified people. If a surplus emerges, it will
not hurt the industry; but it will be a national waste. The government was
similarly hustled into creating a surfeit of engineering colleges in the 1950s.
As a result, when industrial growth slowed down in the 1960s, a chronic surplus
of engineers emerged. Even now, IIT graduates migrate in significant numbers
into other occupations; many of them join the Indian Administrative Service,
and many more go to the management institutes for further education.
Further, a limited familiarity with computers amongst
millions of otherwise poorly educated students is unlikely to help the software
industry. The labour supply problem of the industry is not one of quantity, but
of quality. Young Indians are perfectly familiar with the prospects in
computing, and have for some years been flocking to software training
institutions. Those who can, get into the IITs and engineering colleges; but
many more go to private classes. Their demand has been behind the success of
the two major training companies, NIIT and APTECH. Most of them have taken
secretarial jobs or joined the computer departments of companies and
institutions. What prevents them from becoming programmers is the shortage of
appropriate training facilities.
The only researchers who have probed the sources of
software professionals in some detail are Arora and Arunachalam in a report
they did for the Sloan Foundation. They estimate the annual output of
engineering graduates at 104,000 and of Masters of Computer Applications at
another 10,000. Their estimate of the output of informal training institutes is
about 25,000. If these proportions went back some time in the past and all
engineering graduates and MCAs went into software programming, their share in
the current software work force should be at least 80 per cent. However, they
also estimate that half of the software professionals did not have a degree in
engineering or computer science. They found many chiefs of software firms who
either did not use or were embarrassed about using informally trained people.
That could also lead to their understating the proportion of such people they
are using. This must mean one or more of three things. First, a high proportion
– three quarters or more – of graduates do not enter the industry. Second, a
high proportion of graduate entrants - leave the industry – mainly through
emigration. Or, finally, the output of informal institutes has been
underestimated.
My reading of these admittedly skimpy data is that a
high proportion of the frontline workers in the industry has been trained
informally. The picture is the same in the US industry; according to one
estimate, 41 per cent of the software developers in the US industry were
non-graduates, 45 per cent graduates, and 14 per cent post-graduates. Of the 60
per cent degree-holders, only 40 per cent (i e, a quarter of all workers) had a
degree in software engineering. US output of software graduates is 25,000 –
only about a half of the annual rise in software-related employment. Thus,
graduation is not an essential qualification for entry into software writing.
Twenty per cent of the graduates who enter the industry have specialized in
some other subject than software.
V Labour problems – a nuanced view
In thinking about the labour shortage in the IT
industry, one should distinguish between four types of workers.
i.
Conceptualizers:
Their skill lies in translating a problem or a need into a blueprint for
software to resolve it. Conceptualizers are generally the highest trained in
the IT industry; they often hold doctorates. But their basic qualification is a
flair for thinking algorithmically. Talent is important in this occupation; and
since talent is not taught or transmitted, conceptualizers are highly prized
and paid.
The Indian
industry has relatively few conceptualizers, and hence specializes in the later
stages of software generation. The problem is that there no course of education
for conceptualizers. At some point some Indians will begin to learn the art;
but as long as there is a shortage of conceptualizers, they will be easily
lured abroad. There is little scope for organized action – least of all by the
government.
ii.
Developers:
Developers take the conceptual plans made by conceptualizers and translate them
into reality: they work out the programming inputs required to realize the
concept, allocate the work amongst programmers, and manage the project until a
suitable programme emerges. The demand for them does not come from the domestic
industry alone. Programmers often travel abroad. There they pick up work on
their account; on coming back they start their own firm. The rate of new
business formation in this industry is extremely high. Further, a large
proportion of the employees in this industry try to go abroad – chiefly to
Silicon Valley – and the ones with greater experience and better contacts
abroad are more likely to get a visa or a green card.
This
problem is particularly serious for the Indian industry because its managerial
salaries are limited by its low value added per employee. But even the industry
in Silicon Valley faces the same problem, though to a lesser degree. Its
solution to the problem is stock options – the returns to the employee depend
on the eventual success of the project. But even that is not a complete
solution; eventually, the options must mature, and at that point, employees
will get the choice of leaving.
So a new
solution has been worked out in Silicon Valley. Programmers form transient
teams and hire themselves out to companies. The companies do not employ them;
when the project is over, the team also disappears. This structure shows some
signs of emerging in India; but it is inhibited by the labour laws. This is the
reason for the Subject Group’s stress on the reform of labour laws, and it is
justified
iii. Modifiers/Extenders: These are the foot-soldiers of the industry who
write code, test programmes, modify them and adapt them to changing needs. When
the industry talks of a labour shortage, it is primarily referring to a
shortage in this category. Still, the industry has maintained a growth rate
close to 50 per cent year after year, and has found workers to support it.
The
problem, if any, is with the quality of the training. What the industry needs
is a process of certification. But here, the solution that the Task Force
proposes – that a professional institute should be given a statutory monopoly
of conducting examinations – is misplaced. This is the solution adopted in
accountancy and law; even in these relatively stagnant disciplines, it has
worked poorly. An export-oriented industry like the software industry could
hardly risk obsolescence arising from a monopoly in granting qualifications.
As it
happens, the US industry is facing the same problem, but is trying to solve it
in a different way. The major companies that produced packaged software – for
instance, Microsoft, Cisco, Novell, IBM and Hewlett Packard – already run
examinations to test proficiency in using their programmes. National Skill
Standards Board, an official body, is working Education Development Center and
with the major firms in the industry to work out voluntary certification
standards for the industry. The major Indian firms should similarly try to work
out standards that would be internationally acceptable and would at the same
time fit into their own skill requirements.
(iv) Supporters/tenders: These are workers who do not actually create, test
or modify software, but who run computer-related services within user firms, or
help such firms as consultant trouble-shooters. They also include workers with
computers in IT-enabled services. They do not need to be programmers; but they
need to know the software they have to work with well enough to operate it and
to solve minor problems that it may pose. Of the total IT-related employment of
2 million workers in the US in 1998, programmers were only 626,000; 1.2 million
were “computer systems analysts and scientists”- that is, people who worked
with computers but did not programme. A more recent manpower survey
commissioned by Information Technology Association of America places total
IT-related employment in the US at 10 million; the bulk of it is in technology
support. The additional demand in 2000 was expected to be 1.6 million, of which
600,000 would be in technology support and another 300,000 in database
development/administration. Only 220,000 would be in programming. The
composition of demand in India is very similar; the bulk of the demand is in
organizations that use computers, for workers who do not need sophisticated
knowledge of IT. This demand is being met by the private training institutes,
and will continue to be so met.
Finally, it should be pointed out that the software
industry also faces a threat of brain drain. The difference in wages is the
most important element in the migration. But competition is not equally severe
in all segments of the labour market. Conceptualizers as well as designers are
trained on the job, and their supply is less elastic. They are more often lured
away to the US, and the ratio of their wages in India to those in the US is
high. Modifiers, extenders, supporters and tenders are easier to train, their
supply is more elastic, and their wage ratio is lower. Paradoxically, advances
in information technology are opening up opportunities for services that use
such workers – for IT-enabled services such as accounting, call service and
medical transcription. Thus labour supply will constrain growth differentially
for different sections of the industry; its overall growth need not come down,
but its skill-intensity may. Far from “moving up the value chain”, the industry
may find it makes economic sense to move down it.
Lower prices have been an important reason why it has
secured a foothold in a faraway market despite the handicap that continuous
servicing is important and proximity to the customer is an advantage. But the
ability of the Indian software industry to quote lower prices, as well as to
pay lower nominal wages, depends crucially upon the fact that the purchasing
parity of the Rupee is greater than its exchange rate – that prices in India,
converted at the current exchange rate, are considerably lower than prices in
industrial countries. This is an advantage that India must strive to retain.
Whether it can do so or not depends on monetary and fiscal management, which in
a later article.
Skill requirements in the IT industry
|
||||
Conceptualizers
|
Developers
|
Modifiers/
|
Supporters/
|
|
Extenders
|
Tenders
|
|||
Typical occupations
|
Entrepreneurs
|
System designers
|
Maintenance
|
System consultants
|
Product designers
|
Programmers
|
programmers
|
Customer support
|
|
Research engineers
|
Software engineers
|
Programmers
|
specialists
|
|
Systems analysts
|
Testers
|
Software engineers
|
Help desk specialists
|
|
Computer science
|
Computer engineers
|
Computer engineers
|
Network installers
|
|
researchers
|
Microprocessor
|
Database
|
Network
|
|
Requirements
|
engineers
|
administrators
|
administrators
|
|
analysts
|
Chip designers
|
|||
Systems architects
|
||||
Qualifications
|
||||
Doctoral degree
|
Frequent
|
Occasional
|
Occasional
|
|
Master's degree
|
Frequent
|
Frequent
|
Frequent
|
|
Bachelor's degree
|
Common
|
Frequent
|
Frequent
|
Occasional
|
Associate
|
Occasional
|
Occasional
|
Frequent
|
|
High school
|
Occasional
|
Occasional
|
||
Knowledge required
|
||||
Information technology
|
Critical
|
Important
|
Useful
|
|
Business and industry
|
Useful
|
Useful
|
Important
|
Useful
|
Communication and
|
||||
organization
|
Important
|
Important
|
Important
|
Important
|
VI Customs and import control
Under the Uruguay Round agreement, India is committed to
the abandonment of import licensing by April 1, 2003. But exporters will
continue to be given access to duty-free imports of inputs and equipment. For
this purpose, the government will continue to license duty-free imports; and
trading partners will insist not only that such licensing should continue, but
that it should tie exports and related imports as closely as possible.
Currently there are two types of such licensing
arrangements. For inputs, permissible imports are tied, by means of officially
defined input-output ratios, to individual import transactions. Exporters can
either import inputs duty-free against individual export orders, which makes
ordering of inputs extremely inefficient, or can claim duty drawback after
exporting, which take months to obtain and often involve much corruption. Some
flexibility was introduced into this transaction-by-transaction approach by the
Duty Exemption Pass Book (DEPB), in which import duty is credited when exports
are made and debited when imports are made. But the simplification is
problematic since the implicit connection to transaction is still there, and
the customs can suspend the working of a pass book on suspicion of misuse.
For capital goods, on the other hand, imports at zero
or reduced duty are allowed against a commitment to export goods worth a
multiple of the equipment imports over a number of years under what is called
the Export Promotion Capital Goods (EPCG) scheme. Exporters can avoid both
types of controls by locating themselves in export-oriented zones or their
variants (export-oriented units and software technology parks). But flows of
all kinds – goods, waste materials, manpower – across the border between the
zones and the so-called domestic tariff area (DTA) are policed by the customs.
The policing is the source of most of the complaints
addressed by the Subject Group and the IT Task Force. Of the 84 recommendations
of the IT Task Force on Hardware, 20 relate to customs and import control. The
most important proposal relates to the elimination of customs bonding. The Subject Group proposes exemption of firms
located in software technology parks from customs bonding. The IT Task Force on
software proposes its replacement by an export obligation. The IT Task Force on
Hardware proposes a new category of importer called a soft-bonded IT unit. It
would have a minimum fixed investment (Rs 5 million for a small-scale unit, Rs
10 million otherwise), it would export 25 per cent of its sales, and if it
cannot do so, the difference between its sales and its input imports (including
imputed import duty) would be at least 18 per cent of sales. Such a unit would
import all inputs duty-free, and would be under no obligation to export. But on
whatever it sells in the DTA, it would pay import duties on the embodied inputs
as well as excise duty. The policing of individual import transactions would be
replaced by a legally enforceable undertaking and by audits based on accounts
of input use, to be conducted by private auditors. Transfers of unfinished
goods between soft-bonded units or between such a unit and its subcontractors
would be duty-free; transfer of waste from such a unit to the DTA would attract
import duty, but the unit could declare any value, down to zero, for the waste.
In other words, a soft-bonded unit would pay such duty as it wishes to and an
auditor approves.
Thus, the industry seeks an exemption from customs
bonding for only itself, although bonding is just as vexatious to every other
exporter; textile yarn units, for instance, accumulate mountains of cotton
waste that the customs do not allow to be taken out without payment of
exorbitant duties. And it proposes a remedy that would make it virtually
impossible for the Customs to check whether the correct duty is being paid.
Calculation of duty drawbacks requires data on physical quantities, whereas
business accounts are purely financial. Additional accounts in terms of
quantities could be kept; but they would be no simpler than the present pass
book. Further, if the customs question an exporter’s entitlement to a duty
exemption, the matter is now settled close to the transaction. If the customs
question the entitlement after the annual accounts are prepared and submitted,
the settlement is likely to be much delayed, and the data required to settle it
are more likely to be buried in detail. Hence accounts-based calculation will
be more complicated than transaction-based calculation, and is likely to lead
to more protracted conflict between the customs and exporters.
However, an accounts-based calculation would be
feasible for inputs if all inputs bore the same import duty, and all outputs
bore the same excise duty. Then firms could, when calculating taxes on the
basis of their annual accounts, take excise credit on the proportion of output
that is exported, and import duty credit on the same proportion of inputs. If,
as a special case, all import duties are abolished, then the credit due would
be the sum of excise duty payable on exports as well as on the product of
inputs and the ratio of exports to total sales. If a value added tax replaced
excise, the calculation would be even further simplified: tax paid on imports
would automatically reduce value added and thus be rebated, whilst exports can
be directly exempted from VAT. Thus the ideal system would be one where there
is no import duty at all and a value added tax is levied on imports as well as
domestic sales. That is what India needs quickly to move to.
Manmohan Singh, while he was finance minister, made
considerable progress towards reduction in import duties as well as greater
uniformity. After he left in 1996, the number of rates of customs duties has
continued to come down, but actual rates have gone up. P Chidambaram imposed a
special additional duty of 5 per cent for revenue which was removed last year.
Yashwant Sinha has reduced the number of duty rates, but in doing so has often
raised duties. Under him, the government has also been liberal in yielding to
business demands for anti-dumping duties. And as import licensing requirements
have been removed in conformity with Uruguay Round commitments, they have been
replaced by extremely high tariffs, especially on consumer goods and
agricultural goods.
The process of reducing customs duties needs to be
resumed and taken to its final conclusion, namely zero duties. The sequence may
be the same as in the early 1990s: abolition of the highest rate and its
reduction to a lower one in a series of steps. In the current political
conditions – namely the close connections between the government and protection-seeking
industry – such a process is impossible unless the exchange rate is used to
give matching average protection. A devaluation would be odd when the balance
of payments is so strong; but it is the political price that has to be paid to
get industry’s acceptance for zero duty. Removal of import duty is the only way
of ensuring that the government does not become a partisan player in the game
industries play of agitating for competitive protection.
VII Exchange control vexations
The official position is that the government has freed
current account transactions from exchange control. However, it needs to ensure
that capital account transactions are not disguised as current account transactions.
So transactions over a certain amount need government approval. The limits are
higher for businesses than for individuals; but they are nevertheless real.
Controls on capital movements have also been relaxed; but prior approval is the
rule.
The IT Task Force as well as the Subject Group asked
for relaxation of many exchange control measures for IT firms alone. Thus, for
instance,
(i)
Reserve Bank of
India allows exporters to maintain accounts in foreign exchange, and lets them
make payments up to $25,000 without its approval. This limit should be removed.
Lists of allowable expenses should be expanded.
(ii)
Reserve Bank
expects export proceeds to be received in six months; if the delay exceeds six
months, the exporter has to explain the delay and get permission for
postponement from RBI. The Subject Group wants approval to be dispensed with,
and replaced by simple quarterly reporting.
(iii)
Reserve Bank is
fairly liberal with banking transactions; it is more restrictive about the
transactions it allows against credit cards. The IT Task Force would like to be
allowed to against payment by credit card, and all payments that are allowed
through banks to be allowed against credit cards.
(iv)
Reserve Bank
allows firms to invest abroad p to $25 million or 50 per cent of export
earnings over the previous years, whichever is lower. The Subject Group would
like this limit to be removed. The Task force would like investment in kind to
be allowed.
These and many other demands show that the software
industry is chafing at exchange controls and would like to be exempted from
them. So would every other industry. Whatever relaxations are made should be
made for all industries.
If software export earnings continue to rise at the
rates recently achieved, exchange control will no longer required for
conservation of foreign exchange. Reserves have risen steadily, and that stage
may well have been reached. The question that needs to be asked, therefore, is
whether exchange control needs to be retained for some other reason than to
conserve foreign exchange.
It was proposed in the previous section that there was
a case for abolishing customs duties altogether. If that is done, the
government may well want to retain control on the exchange rate as a means to
influence the terms of trade. Exchange rate targeting requires a high level of
reserves in relation to external payments; especially if the exchange rate
tends to appreciate, it can be held down only if Reserve Bank buys off foreign
exchange. If required actively to manage the exchange rate, Reserve Bank would
also want some control on capital movements.
If Reserve Bank wishes to hold even larger reserves,
it makes sense to liberalize capital inflows. The major categories that are
relevant in this context are:
(i)
Portfolio investment in India by foreign institutional
investors: These have been allowed to
invest since 1991. The limit of investment by all portfolio investors in a
company was limited to 30 per cent of its equity, raised later to 40 per cent
with directors’ approval. The 40 per cent limit should be removed; the limit
should be for the board of a company to decide.
(ii)
Portfolio investment in India by foreign residents: The 1991 reforms excluded personal investors, and
they remain excluded. This exclusion is unnecessary. Portfolio investment by
personal investors should be allowed provided they open bank accounts and use
custodians in India.
(iii)
Foreign direct investment in India by foreign
companies: In the 1991 reforms,
foreign companies were allowed to invest up to 51 per cent of equity without
permission in “priority” industries; investment beyond that level or in other
industries required case-by-case approval. The list of priority industries was
lifted almost without any change from the 1971 policy defining areas which
foreign firms and firms belonging to big business houses would be allowed to
enter. Most of these industries were stagnant and unattractive by the 1990s,
and the liberalization of FDI brought in little investment. Much more foreign
investment came in with case-by-case permission from 1997 onwards. It is now
time to give up case-by-case approval and the variety of limits on equity
holdings. If some industrialists oppose unrestricted FDI and the government is
beholden enough to listen to them, that argues at best for a negative list of
industries with a preannounced limited life, not exceeding five years.
(iv)
Borrowings abroad of Indian companies: The government and Reserve Bank between them keep a
tight leash on these, for fear of a debt crisis. There is a limit on total
borrowings in a year, and Reserve Bank also monitors the maturity pattern. They
reached a peak of $3 billion in 1994, but have been insignificant since. Since
their appetite for loans from abroad has proved limited, there is no need for
restrictions on them any longer.
(v)
Foreign direct investment by Indian companies: Reserve Bank allows FDI by exporting companies
without prior permission up to a certain amount, and with permission beyond
that amount. There are few companies in India with the capital or the will to
make investments abroad. It is now time to allow all Indian companies, whether
they export or not, to make direct investments abroad.
(vi)
Equity issues abroad by Indian companies: The government was fairly liberal with equity issues
abroad. About 70 companies issued equity abroad in the early 1990s. But the
returns on them were so poor that there has been no market for further issues.
The issues are already effectively limited by demand, and do not need to be
restricted by policy.
(vii)
Foreign portfolio investment by Indian residents: Reserve Bank allows Indians returning from abroad to
retain their portfolio investments abroad. But apart from that, portfolio
investment is not allowed at all. The effectiveness of the ban is very
doubtful. Even if Reserve Bank is not prepared to give full freedom of
investment abroad to domestic portfolio investors, it should allow the sale of
a wide range of foreign stocks, bonds and mutual funds in the Indian market.
Indian capital markets are today amongst the most efficient in the world, and
they are heavily underutilized. In the circumstances, trading of foreign
instruments can help the expansion of this industry in which India should have
a comparative advantage.
Thus apart from some temporary controls on foreign
direct investment into India and portfolio investment abroad by Indian
residents, there is little need for exchange control. If Reserve Bank is to
control the exchange rate, and for that purpose needs to hold a minimum level
of reserves, such reserve holdings must be achieved through fiscal and monetary
policy. That is one of their roles. The other is to ensure that the software
export boom is not stifled by exchange rate appreciation; and that the rise in
export earnings is accompanied by maximum real growth and minimum inflation.
VIII How to grow faster
The growth rate of software exports far exceeds the
overall growth rate of real GDP. This cannot continue; at some point, the
growth rate of software exports must slow down, or the growth rate of nominal
GDP in dollar terms must rise. There are four ways in which it can rise:
(i)
The exchange rate
can appreciate. That would make software exports less competitive and bring
down their growth rate; it would also make other industries less competitive,
reduce exports and increase imports. That would be uncomfortable for at least
some domestic industries and would evoke calls for greater protection. We have
argued that import duties and QRs should be avoided: in which case the exchange
rate would be the only instrument of protection; the less it appreciates the
better.
(ii)
The (positive)
differential between domestic and international inflation may rise. Just like
appreciation, it would make domestic industries less competitive, including
software, and worsen the balance of payments. If inflation is demand-led, the
rise in domestic demand could reinforce the worsening of the balance of
payments.
(iii)
The growth rate
of real GDP may rise. This would be the most desirable outcome. Thus, the policy
question boils down to: what policies are needed to raise the elasticity of
supply of aggregate output? This is the question dealt with in this section.
(iv)
Import-intensity
may rise. This requires a reduction in the cost of importing and of transporting
imports inland. This is also dealt with in the next section.
Macroeconomic policies to increase the aggregate
elasticity of supply boil down to three things: increasing the domestic savings
rate, increasing the efficiency of investment, and increasing investment in
infrastructure industries – or more generally in industries which have been a
preserve of the public sector in India and whose growth is handicapped by poor
institutional and legal structures. In this article I shall show how to raise
the savings rate.
Domestic
savings rate: India’s savings ratio
has been in the region of 20-25 per cent for the past 20 years. It has been
significantly lower than in the rapidly growing economies of East Asia (except
Indonesia). As the accompanying Table shows, over 80 per cent of the savings
continue to be “household” (I e, non-corporate private), and 40 per cent of the
household savings are in physical form – that is, in the form of physical
assets or property.
A major
factor that depresses the Indian savings rate and distorts investment is the tax system. It is not the tax rates;
after the reductions in the 1990s, they are today generally lower than in
industrial countries, and not much higher than in comparable developing
countries (except for import duties). It is the tax collectors, who have a
reputation for harassment and corruption. The number of income taxpayers in
India is minuscule compared to the number of people whose income is estimated
to exceed the taxable limit. Finance ministers throughout the 1990s have tried
to raise the number of taxpayers by decreeing that persons with certain
characteristics denoting wealth – a car, a telephone, a trip abroad etc – must
file tax returns; as a result, the number of taxpayers has risen considerably.
But it is doubtful that they will stay in the tax net. The fact is, that
Indians fear tax officials like the plague, and would do anything to stay out
of their records. The fear of the tax official leads to a preference for
consumption over savings, for consumption leaves no trail. It also leads to
greater investment in property and housing; transactions in real estate
typically involve half the payment in cash and half by cheque. It inhibits
investment in the production of goods and services.
Thus, an
honest revenue service is the best way to stimulate savings and direct them
into productive investment. However, a clean revenue service in the middle of
other forms of corruption is not realistic. Elimination of corruption in public
life, therefore, becomes essential for non-inflationary growth.
There can
be a number of ways to remove corruption. For maximum effect, however, there
would have to be reforms affecting the political system as well as the
bureaucracy, and both the senior and the junior bureaucracy.
For the political system, a changeover to a
proportional representation with a high cut-off point for entry into all
legislatures would be desirable. Proportional representation would strengthen
the party vis-Ã -vis the individual politician and shift political funding from
the latter to the former. The cut-off point should be set so high as to ensure
that at most two or three parties would get into a legislature. That would
increase the probability of a party coming to power and increase its average
tenure in power. Parties would then acquire a stake in good government, and
would be less tempted by the chance of using the government to make money. The
incentive to get legitimate party funding can be reinforced by giving parties
state subsidies in proportion to the finance they raise.
The gazetted civil services are at present
recruited from young men and women in their twenties by means of competitive
examinations. The age of entry should be raised to 30, and prior work
experience should count in recruitment. The examination, which at present can
be taken in an absurdly broad range of subjects, should be confined to those
subjects that are required in administration – English, law, accountancy,
economics and mathematics. The present multitude of services should be unified
into one. Salaries at all ages should be comparable to those in the private
sector. Appointment in the civil service should be on contracts of 10 years at
a time, renewable twice at most; and recruitment at the age of 40 and 50 should
be open to mature people from the private sector as well. Shorter contracts
will permit the number of officers at each level to be adjusted to
requirements. At present, officers recruited in their twenties retire at 58.
Consequently there are too many old officers, and posts are created or
appropriated to employ them. Once entry and promotion bars are introduced at 40
and 50, the civil service can be thinned down at higher ages to match the
required command structure.
The junior civil service, consisting of clerks and assistants, is at present chosen
on the basis of examinations that have become a farce. They are appointed for
life, and their promotion opportunities are negligible. This is the major cause
of low-level corruption; it also results in moonlighting and low productivity.
Clerks should be recruited on short-term contracts, not exceeding 5 years; and
they should not be retained beyond the age of 30. At that age they should
either take the entry examination and join the gazetted civil service, or leave
government and go into the private sector. The absence of secure career
prospects will ensure that the government will get young junior employees who
either want administrative training before taking employment elsewhere or who
are bright enough to have a good chance of becoming gazetted officers. Junior
civil service salaries also should be comparable to those in the private
sector.
Saving and Investment Rates
|
||||||
(as percentage of GDP at current market prices)
|
||||||
1993-94
|
1994-95
|
1995-96
|
1996-97
|
1997-98 @
|
1998-99 *
|
|
1 |
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
Household Saving |
18.4
|
19.8
|
18.5
|
17.1
|
19.0
|
18.5
|
Financial |
11.0
|
12.0
|
8.9
|
10.4
|
10.4
|
10.9
|
Physical |
7.4
|
7.8
|
9.6
|
6.7
|
8.6
|
7.6
|
Private Corporate
Saving |
3.5
|
3.5
|
5.0
|
4.5
|
4.3
|
3.8
|
Public Sector
Saving |
0.6
|
1.7
|
2.0
|
1.7
|
1.4
|
negligible
|
Gross Domestic
Saving |
22.5
|
25.0
|
25.5
|
23.3
|
24.7
|
22.3
|
Gross Domestic
Capital |
23.1
|
26.1
|
27.2
|
24.6
|
26.2
|
23.4
|
Formation |
||||||
@ Provisional Estimates
* Quick Estimates |
Source:
Reserve Bank of India (2000).
IX Getting
more out of resources
Last
week I discussed how our low rate of savings could be raised; now it is
necessary to ask, how we can use those savings effectively.
Efficiency of investment can be increased by intensifying
competition in the financial markets. The accompanying Table shows the
composition of financial flows. The figures extend only up to 1995-96, but
there was little change over the previous 10 years, and there is no reason to
think that the picture has changed significantly over the past four years.
The
first point to note is the high proportion of financial investment in currency
and deposits. To keep down the cost of government deficit finance, Reserve Bank
normally plans on growth of money supply of 16-17 per cent a year, which
translates into real growth of about 7 per cent, inflation of another 7 per
cent and an increase in real money balances of 2-3 per cent. The numbers vary
slightly from year to year, but inflation is built into policy. It cannot be
reduced unless growth of money supply is cut down significantly.
The
other important feature is the predominance of non-intermediated fixed-interest
flows – loans and advances, small savings, life insurance funds and provident
funds – which account for almost a half of the total fund flows. India has a
well developed capital market, which has undergone considerable technological
improvement in the 1990s; but in fact it intermediated at most 10 per cent of the
flows. Of these, small savings, life insurance funds as well as provident funds
could be mediated by the market if the government liberalized restrictions on
investment. So could a significant proportion of loans and advances if bill
markets were developed to finance local businesses.
Finally,
a very high proportion of the flows is preempted by the governments: government
securities, securities of banks and financial institutions (most of which
belong to the government), small savings, life insurance funds and provident
funds – which together come to over 20 per cent of the fund flows in most years
– go to the governments. These funds could go into productive investment if the
governments ceased to borrow except for productive purposes. Thus elimination of
the fiscal deficit becomes important for improving the efficiency of investment
as well.
Successive
governments have moved towards a uniform central value added tax by reducing
the number of rates. But this is not enough; the present transaction-based tax
needs to be replaced by an accounts-based tax. Once it is done, the collection
of value added tax and income tax could be unified. In other words, taxes would
be levied on two bases, both calculated from annual accounts – value added tax
and tax on business profits. The tax on profits leads to considerable evasion
as well as avoidance, which can be eliminated by replacing it with the value
added tax. There would then be only two major taxes: a tax on value added by
businesses, and an additional tax on personal incomes above a certain limit.
The
same principle should be applied to state sales taxes: the multiple-rated taxes
should be replaced by a single, uniform value added tax, which could then be
collected together with the central value added tax by means of a surcharge.
The states should, if necessary, be compensated by being allowed to impose
their own surcharges on personal income tax, which may be allowed to vary from
state to state. Different statewise taxes on goods and services militate
against a national common market; but there is nothing undesirable about
differing rates of taxes on persons. This is impossible under the present
Constitution; but it can be provided for in the changes about to be suggested
by the sitting Constitution Commission.
Investment
in industry will go waste unless infrastructure is at hand to support it. An increase in investment in infrastructure
industries requires their privatization and management for profit, together
with introduction of competitive structures where possible and regulation where
free entry and exit are not possible. In all the industries, the latter
segments can be separated: transmission lines in electricity, pipelines in oil,
wired network in telecommunications, the ports in shipping, the airports in air
transport, the roads in surface transport and the track in railways. These
segments should be made subject to the common carrier principle and price
regulation; the rest of each industry should be opened up to competition.
Of
these, the transport infrastructure contributes significantly to the domestic
cost of imports, and an increase in its efficiency will raise import intensity.
Thus, it is well known that Indian ports constitute a bottleneck and yet
utilize only a fraction of their capacity because of a ban on the use of
non-union workers. Mechanization, together with round-the-clock use of the
hauling equipment, would increase port capacity manifold. The capacity shortage
is particularly serious in deep-water ports of which India has few; bulk cargo
is hence transported to better run neighbouring ports such as those of Colombo,
Singapore and Dubai and reshipped in small vessels to India. More intensive use
of deep-water ports could eliminate the reshipment costs.
The
railways massively subsidize second-class and suburban passengers at the cost
of freight. Successive railway ministers have saddled them with enormous
surplus manpower. The railways need to be privatized. Railway tracks should be
hived off into a separate corporation which would rent out the use of fixed
facilities – tracks, sidings, stations and yards. The railway services can be
opened up to competition by dividing up the rolling stock amongst a number of
companies.
The
same principle of separation of transmission lines and supply can be applied to
power. Although the distribution networks must remain regulated monopolies,
they can be divided up into a large number of urban or regional units, each of
which can compete for power. It is possible to demerge the state electricity
boards into a large number of power suppliers. Both the generators and the
buyers must be able to operate in a single national market, mediated by the
national grid. A competitive, unregulated wholesale market for power would also
give an easier entry to cheap hydroelectric power from neighbouring countries.
In
oil and gas as well, the emerging pipeline network must work as a common
carrier network. It would bring down oil transport costs, and make the entry of
new refiners easier. It would also reduce fuel costs with the replacement of
expensive domestic coal by imported oil and gas. Oil- and gas-firing equipment
is cheaper than coal-firing equipment; freer availability of oil and gas would
stimulate wider use of energy and mechanization.
Increase
in capacity and cheapening of transport and transmission would not only raise
import penetration, but it would also, to a much greater extent, stimulate
domestic trade. Thus today, railway freights are so high that it is cheaper to
transport marble to Bombay from Italy than from Rajasthan; cheaper domestic
transport would improve the ability of northern producers to compete in the
expanding markets along the coastline to the west and south.
Flow of funds by
type of instrument (per cent)
|
||||
1986-87
|
1989-90
|
1992-93*
|
1995-96**
|
|
1.Currency and Deposits
|
30.9
|
28.5
|
26.7
|
23.1
|
2.Investments
|
24.9
|
23.6
|
26.2
|
20.4
|
a.Central & state govt securities
|
17.1
|
12.7
|
8.6
|
10.7
|
b.Other Government Securities
|
1.7
|
2.2
|
2.2
|
0.1
|
c.Corporate Securities
|
2.5
|
3.2
|
7.7
|
9.1
|
d.Bank Securities
|
0.9
|
0.5
|
0.4
|
0.6
|
e.Other Financial securities
|
3.6
|
5.7
|
5.9
|
2.2
|
of which
|
||||
i) Mutual Funds
|
0
|
2.6
|
0.9
|
-0.4
|
f.Foreign Securities
|
-0.9
|
-0.8
|
1.4
|
-2.3
|
g.Others
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
3.Loans & Advances
|
23.7
|
26.3
|
29.4
|
37.8
|
4.Small Savings
|
3.6
|
4.9
|
2.1
|
2.1
|
5.Life Insurance Funds
|
2.4
|
2.7
|
3.4
|
3.2
|
6.Provident Funds
|
5.5
|
5.8
|
7.1
|
5.1
|
7.Compulsory Deposits
|
-0.3
|
-0.1
|
0
|
0
|
8.Trade Debt or Credit
|
1.2
|
-0.4
|
-0.2
|
0.2
|
9.Other Foreign claims
|
0
|
-0.1
|
-2.4
|
0.4
|
10.Other items not elsewhere classified
|
8.2
|
8.7
|
7.9
|
7.7
|
T
O T A L
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
*Provisional Estimates
|
||||
** Tentative Estimates
|