Saturday, December 12, 2015

URBAN DESIGN FOR THE 21ST CENTURY

FROM BUSINESS WORLD OF 5 FEBRUARY 2007


Plea for a new type of town


Governments have traditionally given themselves the right of eminent domain – the right compulsorily to acquire private property. The justification given is public interest – for instance, in building roads, ports and airports. Our socialist governments prior to 1991 exercised the right with abandon. They extended it to running businesses as well, many of which they nationalized. And when it suited them, they not only sequestered property, but also expropriated it. For instance, it took away closed textile mills without paying anything for them. Tempted by the central government’s self-appropriated largesse, state governments also helped themselves. In this way, a regime of proprietorial lawlessness came to reign.
This culture of the government helping itself to whatever took its fancy underwent a change after 1991. The government wanted foreigners to invest in India. It did not care what its own investors thought of it, but if foreigners thought that it could just take away their investments, as it did with refineries in the 1970s, they would give India a wide berth. They had done so and gone instead to Southeast Asia; by the 1990s, Southeast Asian economies had a commanding lead over India. The government did not change any laws or give any guarantee against nationalization. But it let it be known that it had changed its stripes. On the basis of this informal assurance, the country has received significant though not copious foreign investment inflows.
Meanwhile, the current boom has led to growing demand for land. As urban property has filled up and its prices have skyrocketed, new enterprises have sought to set themselves up on virgin land. As they spill out of cities, so do the people they employ, who want new residential complexes and multiplexes. And lured by the promise of shining temples of business and burgeoning jobs, state governments have willingly put their powers of compulsory acquisitions at the disposal of companies.
From time to time, these campaigns to remove original residents from sequestered land have erupted into violence. Generally, governments have shot a few, beaten up a few more, and suppressed resistance. But as industrial growth has accelerated, instances of such violent repression have multiplied. They have been particularly endemic in West Bengal, and have brought it unwelcome publicity. But they are not absent elsewhere. As Special Economic Zones proliferate, violent confrontations between landowners and governments threaten to spread escalate.
The central government has been indifferent to the disturbances. But recently it struck the politicians in Delhi that their electoral prospects may be adversely affected by the anger of farmers at forcible acquisition of land. So for acquisition of agricultural land by SEZs, the government proposes to bring legislation that would set minimum standards for compensation to farmers. There is also the idea that ‘fertile’ agricultural land should be exempted from acquisition.
In principle, there should be no difficulty in compensating farmers because the value of land is much greater when it is used for industry, services or urban development than if it is farmed. In fact, it is so much greater that legislation should be unnecessary. It is not because of inadequate compensation for land that West Bengal, Orissa and earlier, Madhya Pradesh, have seen repeated disturbances over compulsory acquisition. The causes are local. In Singur, it was a large section of the population that was employed on the farms but did not own them; it feared loss of jobs, not of land. In Orissa and Madhya Pradesh, it was indigenous people who had no alternative to its traditional subsistence agriculture and that faced the loss of the only livelihood they knew. Gujarat offered the displaced tribals of Narmada valley generous compensation; but inexperience of modern ways – fertilizers, pesticides, markets – made it difficult for them to adjust to a new lifestyle, and many ended up as destitutes and poor landless workers.
Continuous, unencumbered tracts of land often cannot be made available to industry without compulsory acquisition; and it often causes great suffering. Laws on compensation for land, however generous they might be, are quite inadequate and often inappropriate for dealing with the disruption of lives. Such disruption is unavoidable to some extent, but it must be minimized.
There is another reason why the current proliferation of SEZs, industrial zones and residential complexes is undesirable. The more dispersed they are, the greater the traffic they will generate, the greater the fuel consumption and waste of time.

Hence we need to work out how to have maximum development with minimum use of land and multiplication of locations. We should develop a smaller number of larger townships closer to ports and airports. Development should be as vertical as possible, road capacity should be large enough to accommodate long-term requirements, and space should be provided for the pedestrians and peddlers that India inevitably generates. Indian cities of the 21st centuries cannot be like European cities of the 19th century; they must designed around today’s technology.