Thursday, December 10, 2015

CONTROL YOUR TEMPER, KAMAL NATH!

FROM BUSINESS WORLD OF 10 JULY 2006


Bad temper as trade policy


The strong statement made by Kamal Nath as minister of commerce on his return from Geneva is consistent with the position he has taken in the talks directed towards the beginning of a new round of negotiations. So is his decision to leave the meeting two days early.
The basic issue in the Geneva meeting – as it was in the Hong Kong and Doha meetings before it – is that as a precondition for agreeing to a fresh round, developing countries and developed ones are seeking minimum prior commitments to reduce trade barriers. This is a perfectly sensible course; there is no point in trade ministers spending endless days holding meetings in expensive resorts and evenings lavishly entertaining one another unless there is going to be some positive outcome.
The dispute is about the quantum of prior commitments. They are not meant to be precise, but a range is sought to be defined at this stage. The draft on agricultural products is relatively more advanced. It proposes that tariffs would be reduced and tariff quotas expanded subject to exceptions confined in the case of each country to a list of sensitive products. On market access in non-agricultural goods, however, there was no advance towards an agreement at all. The chairman of the the relevant group simply listed the position reached at the time of the Hong Kong ministerial declaration in 2004 with his own comments, but in effect threw up his hands in depair on June 22. Thus there was really nothing further to be achieved, and it would appear that the Commerce Minister was right to abandon a futile meeting and come back to do something more useful.
That would have been the correct impression if the minister had kept quiet. His statements, however, raise the question – indeed, they are intended to force the conclusion – that the breakdown of the negotiations was partly, if not largely due to him. He has said repeatedly –and made sure no one missed the point – that he was not prepared to negotiate on the ‘livelihood and food security interests of millions of India’s subsistence farmers’. This is a politician’s way of saying that the government would not open agriculture to imports.
The negotiating parties in the Uruguay Round were divided between industrial countries which protected their extremely inefficient agriculture with import bans and subsidies, and the Cairns group of efficient agricultural exporters who wanted this protection to be dismantled. The former group bought India’s support by promising to abandon the Multi-fibre Agreement and opening its textile markets to imports from India and other developing countries. In the bargain, it managed to retain its agricultural protection.
Now India has joined the group that wants those industrial countries with inefficient agriculture to open up their markets. But that does not mean that India has joined the efficient agricultural producers. On the contrary, it wants to keep its own agricultural markets closed. In other words, India wants something for nothing.
On its own, it is a pretty unreasonable position to take; no country would be prepared to negotiate with India on that basis. That is why Kamal Nath takes shelter behind millions of subsistence farmers, who he knows will not have anything to say on the subject.
Fortunately, the negotiations are multilateral, and India is only one player. In previous rounds, India got away with equally unreasonable positions by taking shelter behind a cabal of developing countries. And industrial countries let it get away because it was an insignificant player in international trade. Earlier negotiations were basically amongst industrial countries with India sitting on the sidelines and enjoying the reductions other countries made in their trade barriers.
That happy situation is nearing its end. A quarter century of decent growth has made India’s a significant economy; and its high trade barriers have made it a target in trade negotiations.
It is also reaching a break point in its agricultural policy. The green revolution made India self-sufficient in agriculture. There were occasional surpluses of rice and sugar, but the government got rid of them by exporting at a loss. Edible oil was the only major commodity of which India was short; the government made huge profits by levying duties on its imports.

But now India is on the verge of an agricultural deficit. If it keeps its agricultural prices much above the international level, it will have to give large subsidies to imports. There is a very simple way of avoiding the subsidies: open agriculture to international trade at as zero duties. That way, we will import some products and export others. Imports will prevent domestic shortages, and exports will make farmers rich. The country will be better off on balance.