Saturday, December 12, 2015

FINANCE MINISTER, TACKLE INFLATION

FROM BUSINESS WORLD OF 12 FEBRUARY 2007


Waking up to inflation


I have argued for long that the conventional interpretation of India Shining – that India had entered a golden period in which high investment would lead to continuing increases in productivity and high growth would continue for decades – was based on inadequate evidence and that the current boom was triggered off by high liquidity and low interest rates fuelling both investment and consumption. Fortuitously, the Economic Advisory Council to the Prime Minister addressed the consumption part of this view in a report on the economic outlook that it put out in August, and confirmed it. It found that personal loans had accounted for half of the increase in bank credit in the three years up to 2005-06, and had risen from 15 to 25 per cent of total credit. Seeing that bank credit had grown by 32 per cent in 2005-06, it shared Reserve Bank’s preference for slower credit growth; but it wanted more of the credit to go to investment and less to consumption. Looking at prices the way officials do, it was of the view that what inflationary pressure was there was confined to a handful of agricultural commodities – mainly wheat and pulses – and could be dealt with by more liberal imports immediately and higher productivity in the longer run. It noted the sharp fall in share prices in May, but traced it to accentuated international risk perceptions, and concluded that “the market appears to have adjusted, stabilized, and come to a more-or-less neutral position” – in other words, there was nothing to worry about.
Inflation gathered pace, and others in the government got worried about it. So the EAC made another report on inflation in December. It estimated that inflation then was 5.7 per cent and would cross 6 per cent by March. It did not quite put it that way, but it seemed to think that speculators were driving prices up and that better information about crop prospects, more loudly disseminated, would combat their disinformation. To its recommendation of duty-free imports of wheat and pulses, it added reduction of import duties on nonferrous metals.
The EAC’s views have been the basis of the anti-inflationary policies undertaken by the government. Reserve Bank has raised interest rates modestly, slightly increased the cash reserve ratio, and placed restrictions on loans against real estate. The agricultural ministry has imported wheat duty-free. The finance ministry has reduced duties on nonferrous metals. The Forward Markets Commission has banned futures trading in principal pulses. So someone at the helm of economic affairs in the government would carry the impression that it is following an active, well-thought-out, well coordinated, comprehensive policy to keep inflation under control.
Economic policy is made in three steps. First, figures are read and projected. Second, policy options are considered and chosen. Third, as the consequences unfold, policy measures are adjusted. On facts, there are better and worse ways of reading price statistics. My estimates of inflation, together with the likelihood limits, are: food 6.5 (5-8), primary articles 6 (5-7), manufactures 4.2 (3.5-5), overall 5 (4-6). Food price inflation went up sharply in the second half of 2005 when the poor kharif prospects became evident, and has tended upwards throughout 2006. Manufactures price inflation actually came down in the second half of 2005 and fell below 2 per cent by March 2006; it has been going up since.
I think that one reason why agricultural inflation is so high is the stop-go, discretionary agricultural import policy. If the extremely high agricultural tariffs had been brought down or eliminated and imports had been freely allowed, more would have been imported and larger inventories been built up; that would have been far more stabilizing than the syncopated imports by government. Manufacturing inflation has been low because there are no import restrictions and tariffs are generally low.

Reserve Bank can never be relied on to take sufficient and timely deflationary action, both because it would be too afraid of precipitating a crisis, and because with the coming of credit cards and electronic payments, it is losing control on money supply. The onus for anti-inflationary policy is entirely on the finance minister. He should aim at a far greater fiscal correction than is planned under long-term fiscal policy. My preference would be for restraining expenditure; but his party men will, I am sure, have some bright ideas for wasting money. So they would prefer a rise in taxes. Either way, policies against inflation need to be more systemic, more macro and more fiscal.