[As I read management literature in Stanford, I also reflected on my stint in the ministry of finance in the early 1990s, which I had entered with high ideals and flying ambition and left in sadness after being thwarted by one of the minister's favourites. This column was published in Business Standard of 12 July 2000.]
Ambiguity and delinquency
Anyone who has
worked in a large company is aware of the distance between formal hierarchy and
rules on the other hand and working relations and practices on the other. The
distance exhibits itself in the prevalence of cliques – informal groups of
mutually obliging people. They help their members achieve goals, which may be
those of the organization but often are not. Insofar as they are not, clique
members hide the fact. In other words, the rules that are actually practised
are different, often very different from the formal rules. The deviation
sometimes helps achieve the goals of the organization, but sometimes makes it
easier for the clique members to cope with pressures put on them by the
organization. Not everyone can belong to a clique; nor can the entire company
function as a clique. The rules of cooperation and mutual help apply only
within the cliques. Between them there is warfare, generally covert, but which
can break out in the open.
Almost invariably,
the staff employees – that is, the experts and advisers – are kept out of the
line employees’ cliques; the latter work almost systematically to ensure that
the former fail. This endemic conflict can be a perpetual source of frustration
to the top management. It relies on staff to maintain standards and improve
working methods; it sees the work of the staff as being sabotaged by the line
employees. The frustrations make staff jobs less attractive than line jobs, and
build inertia into the organization.
Conversely,
managers and workers’ representatives are by definition in an adversarial
relationship and must keep up an appearance of hostility, or distance at any
rate. And yet, each will want things out of the other; cooperation and
give-and-take arise between the two which often lead in time to the formation
of cliques across hierarchies.
More generally,
wherever people need the cooperation of others over whom they do not have
authority, they will tend to use other weapons – give-and-take, social ties,
go-betweens – which in time tie them together in cliques. Thus at any point of
time, there is a covert organization chart which can often look very different
from the formal one.
The cliques subsist on the mutual exchange of rewards and on the visitation of punishments on
those outside. Many of these can be legal and proper – for instance,
opportunities to travel. Some might be improper but legal; for instance, bigger
daily allowances than required. But many are improper and illegal – for
instance, opportunities to collect commissions and bribes. Where the latter are
used as rewards, a conflict arises between the efficient functioning of the
organization and its viability.
Amongst the rewards
and punishments, the most important are promotion and sidelining. Hence if the
cliques have full sway, it will happen that the most efficient manipulators of
the most powerful cliques will end up at the top, and that ability or merit
will cease to be a criterion in promotion. When an organization riddled with
favouritism faces competition or need for change, it will break out into
wrangling, and fail to meet external challenges.
Melville Dalton
described this picture forty years ago in his Men Who Manage. Many
Indian managers will recognize it. Everywhere, the chief tends to select and
reward people who agree with him and do his bidding. What he looks for is
managers in his own image. What he gets is managers who appear to do his
bidding, but are actually clique leaders good at both getting things done and
sabotaging them. They shape what actually happens, while giving him the feeling
that he is shaping them.
And many people in
the government will recognize that this is more or less how it works. When a
set of politicians with an agenda of its own – for instance, the BJP or Shiv
Sena – takes over, it finds itself stymied by the existing cliques. They get
rid of the current secretaries, and instead put in cronies. Sometimes they get
cronies without cliques, who prove ineffective. Often they get cronies who are
clique leaders, and who get things done for their political masters, but also
for their cliques – for instance, capture posts like Customs Commissioners of
Bombay and Delhi.
The remarkable
thing is that if the organization inducts a “reformer” to revamp it, he will
find himself strongly tempted to take the organization as given. He has limited
freedom to change the people he has to work with. So he takes them for what
they are, and uses what powers he has of reward and punishment to get
performance out of them. If he stays long enough, he develops his own clique or
cliques.
Is that the only
way? Can the reforming executive be no more than a chameleon, changing his
colours to suit the organization? I think the answer is that the effectiveness
of the organization can be changed only by changing the geography of its
cliques. So the first thing he has to do is to understand that map. It will
nowhere be delineated; people will make greatest efforts to conceal it. But it
must be uncovered step by step – by meeting employees, by bringing them
together and observing their chemistry, by inducting individual rewards and
punishments and observing their ripples.
Once he has got the
geography right, the options open to the executive will follow. They are
basically of three sorts. One is to reward the cliques that serve his purpose
and punish those that do not. Another is to reshape the cliques – by moving
people, changing their functions and powers, reorganizing departments. And the
third and the most effective means is to introduce pressures on the cliques
that are goal-oriented. Just which of the three the executive should do will
depend on how long he expects to last and what his powers are. But generally
speaking, he will need to do all three if he wants to maximize his impact.