Thursday, October 2, 2014

REFORMS: WHAT TO DO NEXT

Stanford was charming, but my thoughts turned often to my home country, and to the reforms that I could not carry through. Vajpayee's government had proved more open to reforms, and I had hopes of it. So, early in 2000, I wrote this series in Business Standard.


Whither reforms? 

 

I   A balance sheet of the 1990s

The state of the Indian economy appears to be embarrassingly sound. It is now two years after the nuclear ceremony, which brought universal condemnation and sanctions upon India; just the month before last President Clinton christened our subcontinent the most dangerous spot in the world, thereby telling American business not to invest in India. Despite this confrontation with the capitalist world, India’s balance of payments remains surprisingly strong; through hail and high water, the reserves keep rising.
And that is not because of foreign investment. Foreign direct investment is distinctly down after the coming of the BJP governments. Portfolio investment is not, but it is a fickle bird of fancy. It has been down and up. It is here today and may be gone tomorrow. In any case, capital inflows are not responsible for the rising reserves. One cannot avoid the conclusion that the external fundamentals are strong.
And more surprisingly, inflation is down. The level of inflation showed a distinct fall from 1996 onwards; in the past year it has come down to levels that have not been seen since the days before socialism and the grand follies. Something has changed; we are no longer in the boom-and-bust mode of the 1960s, 1970s or 1980s.
What has changed? Five things in particular. First, industry is no longer in a position to pass on cost increases. Domestic competition has increased, and now there is some competition from abroad as well. This accounts for much of the fall in inflation. For this, the credit must go to the Fund and the Bank, which forced us to abolish industrial licensing in 1991, and to Narasimha Rao who had the sense to yield to force. If the Fund and the Bank had any strategic sense, they would be advertising their success in India instead of drawing comfort from Côte d’Ivoire and El Salvador.
Second, the illegal balance of payments has collapsed. The havala premium has disappeared, and billions of dollars that used to be siphoned off into illegal foreign exchange transactions have come into the legal channels. For this, credit again goes to the Fund and the Bank – they forced us to devalue in 1991, begin to dismantle import licensing in 1992, and start reducing tariffs in 1993 - and to Manmohan Singh at the Finance Ministry and P Chidambaram at the Commerce Ministry who carried out these changes. But I would now give greater credit to Chidambaram. For when Manmohan Singh liberalized gold imports through NRIs without releasing foreign exchange for them, he in effect legalized smuggling; most of the gold came to be brought in by couriers of big Dubai smugglers. When Chidambaram allowed a few banks to import and sell gold in 1996, he dug the grave of gold smuggling. We see the effects of this single measure today in the death-throes of havala. The rise in the reserves is due to the fall in the demand for gold and smuggled goods, and in foreign exchange balances illegally held abroad.
The third change is something Manmohan Singh did in a moment of righteousness. He felt it was unfair that the government should take away people’s savings without a by-your-leave through the loans it compulsorily sold to the banks. So he resolved in 1992, without anyone asking him, that the central government and its institutions would no longer resort to the Statutory Liquidity Ratio. On the face of it, it changed nothing; even now the Reserve Bank sells thousands of crores of central securities to the banks. But the absorption is no longer automatic; the Reserve Bank has to cajole, threaten, twist arms, and even then it sometimes cannot sell the loans. It has had to raise interest rates; the cost to the government has gone up. IDBI and ICICI have had to raise money from retail investors at high interest rates. The change is working its way through the system. When Yashwant Sinha inveighs against the fiscal deficit, he is not being a reformer; he is just reflecting the consequences of Manmohan Singh’s decision.
The fourth change is in taxation. Manmohan Singh brought down the income tax rates. If I write that revenue has increased as a result, Mr S S Bagai will immediately write back showing that it has not as a proportion of non-agricultural income. But I would still claim that that in a country where tax evasion is so rife, all taxation is unfair to honest taxpayers; the reduction in taxes has evened the scales slightly in their favour. It is not just the tax reduction; there are two further fiscal changes. One is that the rate of corporate tax and the peak personal rate of tax are about the same, so the gains from declaring personal expenses as corporate expenses have declined, and so have the advantages of controlling companies for that purpose. And Yashwant Sinha abolished the tax on dividends in the hands of shareholders, and thereby reduced the double taxation of dividends (as against the single taxation of undistributed profits). This too reduced the advantage of controlling companies. With these two changes, a promoter no longer has to control a company to be able to live off its profits; he can hand it over to competent managers and live comfortably as a shareholder. A handful of promoters have done so already; many more have hired more competent CEOs than themselves.
The last change is not very clear to me: something has happened in the foodgrain market. In the 1970s, the green revolution created a flood of wheat; to save Punjabi farmers from distress, the central government turned the rationing scheme into a scheme to subsidize foodgrains and increase their consumption. But there are always many claimants for a subsidy: farmers, who would like higher prices, consumers, who would like lower prices, and the officials of Food Corporation, who would like fat margins to blow up on themselves. The farmers have politically been the most powerful, and have won an annual support price increase of 10-15 per cent year after year. That is what raised the rate of inflation from an average 7 per cent in the 1950s and 1960s to 11 per cent in the 1980s, even though the growth rate of foodgrain output rose. In the 1990s, somehow, the political advantage of pushing up support prices petered out. The first sign came in the eight state elections of 1994-95, of which the Congress lost six. Manmohan Singh connected this to Balram Jakhar’s pushing up of support prices by 60 per cent in three years. He applied all brakes and brought down inflation to an incredible 4 per cent by the general election of 1996; but the Congress still lost. The present government is, if anything, even more beholden to Punjabi farmers; but it has been more circumspect in raising support prices. The urban supporters of the BJP have at last found a voice. So inflation has come down, and I think the fall may last.
These five changes have buttressed the economy and opened up great opportunities. In the next article I shall suggest how the momentum imparted by these reforms can be maintained.




II   The five best reforms



Some months ago I wrote a series on the pending reforms. That series was more for reform aficionados; it was meant to outline what in my views would be real reforms and not pseudo-reforms. They were not what is going to happen; our political system is creaky and cranky that it would take centuries to put through such a programme of reforms even if we had statesmanlike leaders and reasonable followers. Given the limited capacity of the system for change, it is worth making a short list of the things that are most worth doing. In my view, they are five.

1.    Abolition of customs duties: This sounds radical, but is not. We have reduced the maximum rate of duty from 350 per cent in 1991 to 38.5 per cent today and the average rate from 48 per cent to 29 per cent; now it is only a matter of reducing it to zero. It would pose no threat to industry; all we have to do is to make the appropriate devaluation to keep industries afloat. It cannot exceed 38.5 per cent; it will probably be more like 15 per cent. Nor would it mean the end of all import taxation; imports should still bear the single-rated value added tax (see 2 below). Amongst the advantages, it would become impossible for politicians to favour one industry against another and for firms to use customs duties in their competitive wars; and zero duty would make duty drawbacks for export industries unnecessary, and thereby abolish the huge empire of corruption and export discouragement that the customs department and the DGFT have built up. Caution: if customs duties are abolished, the exchange rate would be the only instrument for holding the balance between domestic industry and imports, and would have to be managed for that purpose. That means some controls on capital flows; full convertibility is out.

2.    Integration of business and commodity taxation: There should be a single rate of value added tax, which would replace the present excise duties, state sales taxes, and corporate income tax. It would be a tax on value added generated in all businesses. It would be calculated just like the corporate income tax, except that the base would be value added, and not profits. The base would be much larger, and hence the rate would be much lower. A single tax collection agency can replace the Central Board of Excise and Customs, the corporate tax arm of the Central Board of Direct Taxes, and the revenue departments of state governments; the fewer the collectors, the less the harassment and corruption. The base rate of VAT would act as a base rate of personal income tax on all employees and businessmen. There can be one or two higher brackets of personal income tax. Caution: Although the tax would be based on annual accounts and become due once a year on their finalization, its collection may be spread out over the year just as with the present corporate income tax.

3.    Government borrowing only for fixed investment: Curbs on government borrowing are in the air. What is wrong is not that the governments are borrowing, but they are borrowing without lenders’ consent and spending the money on unproductive expenditure. The statutory liquidity ratio should be abolished; banks should no longer be forced to lend to the governments. A law should be made that governments may raise debt only in the market, and can finance only productive fixed investment with it. They would thus be forced to consider their servicing capacity before borrowing, and to use borrowings for investments that would lead to a rise in revenue.

4.    Separation of cash holding and investment: At present banks provide two services in a package: they hold cash for depositors, and invest it in loans, government bonds etc. The two businesses should be separated. All banks should be made to offer a pure cash holding service to depositors, on which they would pay no interest and may levy charges. The cash holdings would be simply entries in a central computer owned by the Reserve Bank; they would be completely secure, and transferable at will. In addition, banks may offer their depositors the option of investing the money in packages, which may consist of loans to borrowers of a particular credit rating, bills of exchange, bonds, shares or mutual funds. They should have to disclose to the investors the full risks of investment in a particular channel. The investors should bear all the risks of non-payment of interest or principal, or of bankruptcy. That would end pre-emption of savings by banks, as well as accumulation of bad debts by them. Caution: Government banks would have to be privatized; otherwise they would continue to lend by preference to the government and be subject to politicians’ whims. Although cash holding would become a very simple business and anyone should be allowed freely into it, only banks that can offer their depositors a certain minimum range of choice should be allowed into the business of investing depositors’ savings. That means continued licensing of such banks. Reserve Bank should organize and run local markets for bonds and bills, and thereby securitize as much of bank debt as possible. Packaging of loans of similar credit rating would permit banks to pay rates of interest reflecting the risk; depositors would thus be able to choose different risk-return combinations. Interest spreads and investor choices would determine the volume of credit available to businesses of different sizes and risk levels; the present tendency of banks to fund large, low-risk borrowers would disappear.
5.    Dereservation of small industry: Small industry reservation should be abolished. It was never needed. The evidence is that small firms pay lower wages and can compete perfectly well with big ones, and have vanquished large firms in many industries. Most of the 800-odd reserved products are not important to small firms; and few small firms depend much on reserved products. The other concessions – directed credit, tax concessions, industrial estates, government purchases – favour a small number of small firms. What these privileges have achieved is to punish those small firms that grow beyond the small industry thresholds; they have thus thwarted the growth of precisely those firms that could make India internationally competitive. Instead of small firms, new start-ups should be favoured by means of a five-year tax holiday from the single-rated value added tax proposed above. Caution: Such a tax holiday could lead to tax evasion: firms might be wound up after five years and restarted under another name. Profits on liquidation should therefore be taxed.

I think that these five reforms would do more than anything to make India more competitive, to limit licence-permit raj, and to unleash the forces of growth. But they are not the kind of things that appeal to politicians, least of all to BJP politicians. So in the next article I shall take up the types of initiatives that appeal to them, and describe how they can be made more rational and effective.




III   Reforms BJP-style


Although the five reforms I suggested in the last article would do most to dynamize the economy, they are not the kind that would appeal to politicians. Politicians are players in a political game, and they want winning strategies that would win them the loyalty of the electorate and the contributions of rich friends for decades to come. They long for the kind of dream run the Congress had for forty years. Some of them also have ideals. They are looking for winning formulae, and have pursued a number of agendas with that aim. Let me take up those agendas and show how best they are pursued.

1.    Employment: We slick townsmen cannot imagine how the problem of employment haunts politicians. Members of Parliament and MLAs are pursued by job-seekers. Once they get into power, their survival depends on their giving jobs to their supporters. Hence the popularity of Lallu Yadav, a shameless rewarder of supporters; hence the hold of reservations on our political system; hence the longing of every politician from Bihar and Bengal for the railway ministry, one of the last ministries which can still be loaded with useless supporters. On employment, a liberal’s view is that employment should be productive, and that it should be created in the private sector by macro-measures which do not favour one constituent against another. Hence in the liberal view, faster growth of production is the key to faster employment growth. A liberal favours openness because he believes that international trade will enable each country to employ more of its abundant resources – for instance, labour in India. Although being a democrat he will not say so loudly, a liberal distrusts trade unions, which he thinks raise wages and reduce the demand for labour. This is all correct; but it is not going to satisfy politicians who depend on local electorates thirsty for jobs. My own thinking is that industry could absorb much labour 150 years ago; since then so much labour-saving technology has been developed that industry cannot be efficient and give many jobs. Agriculture, on the other hand, is hugely inefficient and will shed jobs if given a chance. Jobs can be created only in services. They are being created there and will continue to be. But services require interaction with buyers, and have to be produced wherever they are sold. Hence mobility of labour is all-important to service jobs. It will be helped if transport services are good and cheap, there is housing everywhere for the poor, and they are educated to be versatile and to communicate well. Transport, housing and education are also top priorities of the BJP; to these I go on.

2.    Transport: The Prime Minister’s cross of roads has attracted much criticism, including from me. But the spirit behind it is laudable: the idea is to employ people and cheapen transport. Except that a north-south road and an east-west road are poor ways of doing it. Good roads these days are highly material- and capital-intensive: they are made of reinforced steel and concrete, and making them with big machinery saves time and hence money. Nor are new roads the cheapest way of increasing road capacity; it is cheaper to widen the roads that are there, to remove bottlenecks, and to improve road surface. Of the three ways, the last is the most labour-intensive. To create employment, the governments should give out long-term contracts to improve the surface of and to maintain particular stretches of roads; the payment for the contracts should depend on the minimization of potholes and other defects. Transport costs are raised and delays caused by states’ and local authorities’ checkposts. Their removal will increase road capacity and actually lower total costs.

3.    Housing: The BJP as well as the NDA manifestos placed great stress on housing. Ram Jethmalani got the Urban Land Ceiling Act repealed – with little effect, since most states continue to impose the same restrictions. Yashwant Sinha has allocated money each year for housing schemes. But these are not the means to improve housing cheaply and quickly. What India needs is housing for the poor. The cheapest housing the poor can get is what they themselves build. Unfortunately, it is low-rise and hence wasteful of land; and since they cannot buy land, they squat, mainly on public land. The solution that is popular with politicians is to remove the poor from their squats, give them land on city outskirts and help them build little houses. Sanjay did it, so did Thackeray, with little effect. Apart from disrupting lives, it only shifts the current poor; they are soon replaced by new squatters. The solution is to release land – public land, or land purchased from private owners – for standardized high-rise housing made up of small flats in which none but the poor would want to live; if the costs are so high to take the flats beyond the poor’s reach, their building should be subsidized. Lower interest rates would help; but not the poor, for they would also raise land prices.

4.    Education: Murli Manohar Joshi has been very active. But his agenda is only ideological and political: he would like to introduce Bharatiya Samskriti into education and find jobs for BJP supporters. This is a very narrow agenda. What matters is taking education to the poor, and giving them education that would enable them to diversify their skills and improve their communication ability. For this, what they really need to learn is languages – not just their mother tongue, but languages of states where employment is available, and English – and arithmetic. The way to make such education widely accessible is to impart it on television; today, DTH television, which can send 200 channels at a time, offers an ideal medium for education. Government schools are no answer; they are just havens for teachers who teach little. The answer is to give children vouchers to attend any school they want.

5.    Technology: Starting from the Prime Minister, BJP politicians are enthused by the software success and would like to replicate it on a large scale. The instruments are there in the universities and government laboratories. They all need to be privatized and liberated from government rules on appointments, promotions, pay etc; they must also finance themselves, which they will do by selling research. Subsidies should go, not to institutions and their staff, but to students and to equipment. Recruitment in the institutions should be opened up, not only to all Indians, but to the best from anywhere in the world. Just as America drains away our best brains, let us drain Pakistan, Bangladesh, Egypt, Kenya and other neighbours of their brains.

Thus, the aims chosen by the BJP are worth pursuing; but the instruments they choose are unlikely to succeed. If they want to achieve anything in the directions of their choice, they will have to look for economic solutions – and those solutions will not be such as to suit their predilections.